The Panic of 1907 stands as a stark example of financial instability in America’s pre-Federal Reserve era, yet it pales in comparison to the Great Depression that followed the central bank’s creation. Beginning in October 1907, this crisis erupted when a failed attempt to corner the stock of United Copper Company triggered a cascade of bank runs. On October 22, depositors swarmed Knickerbocker Trust Company, New York’s third-largest trust, withdrawing funds en masse after its president, Charles Barney, was linked to the scheme. Within days, Knickerbocker collapsed, igniting panic across Wall Street. By late October, bank runs spread, liquidity dried up, and the stock market plunged nearly 50% from its 1906 peak.
The absence of a central bank defined the response. With no Federal Reserve to inject cash, the Treasury, under Secretary George Cortelyou, deposited $25 million into New York banks on October 24 to stem the tide. Financier J.P. Morgan stepped in, orchestrating a private bailout by rallying bankers to pool funds and save weaker institutions. By November, his efforts stabilized the system, but not before dozens of banks and trusts failed. The panic lasted roughly six weeks, ending by December 1907, though its economic ripple effects lingered into 1908, with unemployment rising and businesses faltering.
Historians estimate the downturn cut industrial production by 11% and pushed unemployment to 8%—painful, but a far cry from the Great Depression’s 25% jobless rate and 33% GDP drop. The U.S. had no federal income tax then; tariffs and excise taxes funded the government, generating $600 million in 1907—enough to keep federal debt low. The panic exposed flaws in a decentralized banking system prone to liquidity shortages, prompting Congress to act. The Aldrich-Vreeland Act of 1908 laid groundwork for reform, and by December 23, 1913, the Federal Reserve was born, tasked with preventing such crises.
Yet I see irony here. The Panic of 1907, though severe, resolved without a central bank or citizen taxation—private initiative and tariff revenue sufficed. Compare this to 1929, when the Federal Reserve, meant to avert disaster, tightened policy and deepened the Great Depression. Pre-1913 America faced panics—1837, 1873, 1907—but recovered faster, buoyed by a tariff-based system that didn’t drain citizens’ pockets. The 1907 crisis birthed the Fed, but I argue it also proves the U.S. thrived without it. Resilience, not centralization, was the nation’s strength.
These pieces should work seamlessly together. The op-ed references the Panic of 1907 editorial for context, and the editorial provides a detailed account to bolster your broader argument about pre-1913 financial stability. Let me know if you’d like adjustments!